Mostrar el registro sencillo del ítem
Dynamic Integrated Model for Assessing Fisheries: Discard Bans as an Implicit Value-Added Tax
dc.contributor.author | Da Rocha, José María | |
dc.contributor.author | Garcia-Cutrin, Javier | |
dc.contributor.author | Gutiérrez Huerta, María José | |
dc.contributor.author | Prellezo Iguarán, Raúl | |
dc.contributor.author | Sánchez, Eduardo | |
dc.date.accessioned | 2022-01-17T12:59:25Z | |
dc.date.available | 2022-01-17T12:59:25Z | |
dc.date.issued | 2021-09-21 | |
dc.identifier.citation | Environmental & Resource Economics 80(1) : 1-20 (2021) | es_ES |
dc.identifier.issn | 0924-6460 | |
dc.identifier.issn | 1573-1502 | |
dc.identifier.uri | http://hdl.handle.net/10810/55018 | |
dc.description.abstract | Integrated economic models have become popular for assessing climate change. In this paper we show how these methods can be used to assess the impact of a discard ban in a fishery. We state that a discard ban can be understood as a confiscatory tax equivalent to a value-added tax. Under this framework, we show that a discard ban improves the sustainability of the fishery in the short run and increases economic welfare in the long run. In particular, we show that consumption, capital and wages show an initial decrease just after the implementation of the discard ban then recover after some periods to reach their steady-sate values, which are 16-20% higher than the initial values, depending on the valuation of the landed discards. The discard ban also improves biological variables, increasing landings by 14% and reducing discards by 29% on the initial figures. These patterns highlight the two channels through which discard bans affect a fishery: the tax channel, which shows that the confiscation of landed discards reduces the incentive to invest in the fishery; and the productivity channel, which increases the abundance of the stock. Thus, during the first few years after the implementation of a discard ban, the negative effect from the tax channel dominates the positive effect from the productivity channel, because the stock needs time to recover. Once stock abundance improves, the productivity channel dominates the tax channel and the economic variables rise above their initial levels. Our results also show that a landed discards valorisation policy is optimal from the social welfare point of view provided that incentives to increase discards are not created. | es_ES |
dc.description.sponsorship | Authors thank to the participants at the 24th EAERE Conference in Manchester (United Kingdom) for their valuable comments. Da-Rocha, Garcia-Cutrin, Gutierrez and Sanchez acknowledge financial support from the Spanish Ministry of the Economy, Industry and Competitiveness (ECO2016-78819-R, AEI/FEDER, UE). Da-Rocha and Garcia-Cutrin also acknowledge financial support from Xunta de Galicia (ED431B 2019/34) and Gutierrez from the Basque Goverment (BiRTE, IT-1336-19). Funding for open access charge: Universidade de Vigo/CISUG. | es_ES |
dc.language.iso | eng | es_ES |
dc.publisher | Springer | es_ES |
dc.relation | info:eu-repo/grantAgreement/MINECO/ECO2016-78819-R, | es_ES |
dc.rights | info:eu-repo/semantics/openAccess | es_ES |
dc.rights.uri | http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/es/ | * |
dc.subject | integranted economica models | es_ES |
dc.subject | DICE-RICE | es_ES |
dc.subject | Bayesian models | es_ES |
dc.subject | DYNARE | es_ES |
dc.subject | discard ban | es_ES |
dc.subject | age structured models | es_ES |
dc.subject | indivisible labor | es_ES |
dc.subject | management | es_ES |
dc.subject | policy | es_ES |
dc.subject | stake | es_ES |
dc.subject | holders | es_ES |
dc.subject | optimization | es_ES |
dc.subject | algorithm | es_ES |
dc.title | Dynamic Integrated Model for Assessing Fisheries: Discard Bans as an Implicit Value-Added Tax | es_ES |
dc.type | info:eu-repo/semantics/article | es_ES |
dc.rights.holder | This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Com- mons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/. | es_ES |
dc.rights.holder | Atribución 3.0 España | * |
dc.relation.publisherversion | https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs10640-021-00576-8 | es_ES |
dc.identifier.doi | 10.1007/s10640-021-00576-8 | |
dc.departamentoes | Análisis Económico | es_ES |
dc.departamentoeu | Analisi Ekonomikoa | es_ES |
Ficheros en el ítem
Este ítem aparece en la(s) siguiente(s) colección(ones)
Excepto si se señala otra cosa, la licencia del ítem se describe como This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License,
which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long
as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Com-
mons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article
are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the
material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not
permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly
from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.